2015년 9월 15일 화요일

Volatility Smileless

Volatility Smileless
Wonyoung Choi                                                                               2015-9-16



Volatility skew is a phenomenon that implied volatility (IV) increases as option becomes increasingly in-the-money (ITM) or out-of-the-money (OTM) (quoted from the figure below). It has a parabolic shape and because of the shape it is called 'volatility smile' also as shown below. I assume that readers of this paper are familiar with options and the Black-Scholes option pricing model in theory and in practice.


Fig. 1 Volatility Skews[1]
Fig. 2 Volatility Smile[2]

The lowest point appears usually at-the-money (ATM) but often happens off the ATM, which is called smirk by some people as shown below.

Volatility smirks[3]

An example of the volatility skew in the real world is shown below. The chart shows smile, smirk, and call-put gap.
The smirk: this happens quite often and (I think) is a very interesting phenomenon but will not be discussed in this paper.
The smile (shape): Natenberg wrote "One inference which most traders draw from this shape is that the marketplace appears to believe there is a better chance for a large price move in the real world than is predicted by the Black-Scholes model."[4] He also wrote "Unfortunately, dealing with a volatility skew can be a problem because there is no exact formula to use as guide." This will be studied in this paper.
The call-put gap: this happens quite often and (I believe) I have explained in my earlier paper[5] and will be discussed in this paper.



Fig. 3 Volatility Skew in reality

In the real world example above, some values are plotted with a smooth curve while others are very erratic. The primary reason is that ITM options usually have ask-bid gaps. So, the data show only the last transacted prices, not the (real) current prices. So, usually the volatility skew or smile is plotted only with OTM options, puts and calls. Deep-OTM (DOTM) options have very low prices. Once the price reaches the minimum tradable price, 0.01 in Korea, it remains the same for all the other deeper OTM options. Deeper strike prices (usually symbolized as "X") automatically raise the IV which makes the smile shape. So, it is not meaningful to plot options from and below the minimum price. Hereafter, I will plot only ATM and OTM options above the minimum price, call and put, to chart the volatility skew. Figure 3, then, looks like figure 4. Figure 4 shows an extreme reverse skew.


Fig. 4 IV of ATM and OTM options over min price

The call-put gap

The call-put gap happens because of the futures basis gap and can be eliminated by applying the adjusted underlying asset (usually symbolized as "S") to the Black-Scholes model (Choi, 2012). In this example, S (K200 in Korea, the basket of 200 big companies) is 233.54, which is used in the computation of IV in the home trading system (HTS) and by the regulating authorities. KOSPI200 futures is 233.55. The theoretical value of KOSPI200 futures is 234.44 and so the futures gap is -0.89. The adjusted S is calculated as K200+gap, in this case 233.54 - 0.89 = 232.65. IVs calculated with this adjusted S are charted below, clearly showing the removal of the gap.



Black-Scholes model requires the price of the underlying asset S to calculate the price and all the Greeks. However, S, KOSPI200 in this example, is not tradable practically. So the futures of KOSPI200 is used in practice as a surrogate for option trading decision making and hedging. The gap is, I think, solely due to this surrogation. The gap is almost completely eliminated by applying the adjusted S. The gap is proportional with the futures gap, i.e., the bigger the futures gap, the bigger the option call-put gap. This is natural and purely computational because arbitrage should make it happen: so-called compound futures made with some combinations of calls and puts can be traded together with futures of the opposite direction with some risk-free gains made instantly.

The smirk

The smirk (similar to skewness in statistics but, to distinguish the smile or the shape, this word is used) is surely related with the futures gap because the futures gap moves the ATM. In this sense, the smirk is computational. However, it seems that market psychology is also involved: first, the smirk seems to be too wide for the futures gap; second, the Greeks seems to be distorted too much, which will be mentioned in the shape issue.

The smile (shape)

I doubt what Natenberg mentioned about the smile quoted above. I think that the smile (i.e., the further off the ATM, the higher the IV) should reflect some cost or benefit. Natenberg's quote says that the smile is basically psychological (he said "the marketplace appears to believe") while I believe that there should be some computational or mathematical factor(s). Among the Greeks, gamma and vega (kappa) are favourable to options while theta is the opposite. So, it can be hypothesized that gamma or vega (these two are highly correlated) demand higher prices for options while theta accepts lower prices. The first step to take would be to check the correlations of IV with Greeks. The results are very interesting. The correlation coefficient between IV and gamma/vega are about -0.9 and +0.9 for theta in many actual cases, if the strike prices of options do not include the lowest IV point. However the smirk is a problem here too. Call or put that includes the lowest IV have a parabolic shape while the Greeks are not, which makes the correlation coefficient almost 0. Still, the correlation coefficient beyond the lowest point is again about ±0.9. The smirk interval also has the correlation coefficient about 0.9 but with the opposite sign.

To neutralize the effect of smirk, instead of removing the smirk range, I extended put plotting range into the ITM up to strike price with the lowest IV and the result is charted below. The chart plots calls the smirk range.  The correlations are calculated for puts with a range of X from 192.5 to 250, the lowest IV, and for calls from 252.5 to 270. The correlation coefficients are -0.94 for puts and -0.91 for calls.

Actual data and chart (ATM 240, lowest IV 250)
With adjusted S and only over min. price. Call only OTM and ATM, put extended to the lowest IV

The following chart plots residuals after applying linear regression with vega (same result with gamma). Please note that calls are shifted upward to equalize the average of the residuals. The shape strongly suggest (especially for puts) that these could be some other factor or variable and the range of the residuals is too wide (out of the original IV range 23% points, the regression eliminated only 14%, leaving the residuals with about 9% range).


In conclusion, I hypothesize that the so-called volatility smile does NOT exist if the IVs are compensated with the Greeks.
The cause/effect of the smirk needs further study and tests.

End.




[1] Natenberg, Sheldon, Option Volatility & Pricing, 1994, McGraw-Hill, p.408
[3] Ibid.
[4] Natenberg (1994), p.407
[5] Choi, Wonyoung, "Modification of Black-Scholes model for Korean market" (in Korean), (2012)

댓글 없음:

댓글 쓰기